The Poor are Getting Richer, Too

Over at Carpe Diem, Mark Perry has a pair rather interesting charts:

incomeshares1incomeshares

These charts show US household shares in various income groups in constant (that is, inflation-adjusted) dollars.  For example, the bottom chart shoes that 24.7% of US households in 2014 earned $100,000+ per year.

Mark’s point with these charts is that the Middle Class is disappearing, but they are moving into the upper class.  That certainly is true: in both charts, the Middle Class’ shares are lower in 2014 than they were in 1967.  I think is also a major take-away from this is the decline in the Lower income group as well.  In both cases, the Low-Income group’s shares are falling as well.  In real terms, this means that fewer and fewer US households are in the bottom levels of society.  So, the rich are getting richer, but the poor are getting richer, too.

This data is confirmed in a report by the Financial Times.

The 1960’s may have been the height of the Middle Class, but it looks like the 2000’s will be the rise of the Upper Class

 

Freedom of Movement Prevents Monopolies

Freedom of movement is one of the essential freedoms (the others being trade, self-defense and speech).  Freedom of movement prevents all kinds of tyranny, not only government-imposed, but also privately-imposed.

Concentration of power is only effective because it is concentrated.  The US government only has power over the US.  The New Hampshire General Court only has power over New Hampshire.  Unitil only has a monopoly in Southern New Hampshire.  By being able to move out of these areas, it limits the ability for the powerful bodies to exercise their power on any given individual.

This also explains why it’s damn near impossible for monopolies to form outside of government protection.  Even if a store has 100% market share in a particular region, one can always use his freedom of movement to go and shop at another store.  Therefore, it reduces any kind of monopoly (or monopsony) power a firm might have in normal (that is, no government interference) conditions.  Especially, in this digital age, this movement is very easy.  It needn’t even be physical.  From my apartment, I can shop from anywhere in the world.

Wal-Mart’s ability to “exploit” their workers or “exploit” their customers is severely limited by the fact people can choose to patronize other locations.  As long as people are free to move, then any claims of monopoly and monopsony in a free market are highly suspect and should be subject to extreme intellectual scrutiny.

Charity Need Not Stand Alone

One of the common arguments for the welfare state is that charity cannot solve all the world’s ills, that government must step in to fill the hole.  But charity is not the only game in town; it’s not an all-or-nothing proposition.  The gigantic elephant in the room, the one with the most power to create wealth, is the free market.

The market’s power to combat social ills (such as poverty and all its associated ills like malnutrition) is gargantuan.  Since the fall of the Soviet Union, the world has moved toward more economic freedom.  During this same time, we’ve seen global poverty plummet , violence fall, food consumption in the developing world increase, and all manner of other good things.  Jason Furman, President Obama’s economic adviser, did a study finding that Wal-Mart alone saves Americans about $895 per person per year.

Charity can supplement the good works done by the market.  It can help those who fall through the cracks.  Charity is an important aspect of life.  Markets can do the hard work, and charity can help finish up the job.  Government, too can help by ensuring fair play: protecting the rights of everyone.

The Uses of Fiction

This month’s featured article at EconLog is by Matthew Rousu on economic lessons from The Hunger Games.  The article is a very good read.  However, in an EconLog post promoting the article, a commentator objected:

Oh come on, please don’t use a fictional place to prove a point. I enjoyed the Hunger Games books and movies as a revolution to knock off the bad guys. But the economics in that society make no sense. The author can make any society as rich or poor as he/she wishes, regardless of how real societies evolve. Do I really need to point this out?

This commentator is right that an author can make a book say pretty much anything they want, but fiction can still be a useful way of looking at society and learning economics.  You can re-read my posts on the economic lessons of Mass Effect beginning here.  I also recommend Josh Hall’s Homer Economicus.  Thomas Piketty does this in his book Capital in the 21st Century.  We could also cite any number of allegorical works, such as Animal Farm, Aesop’s Fables, Dr. Suess, The Giver, the list goes on!

The practice of using parables to make points is literally ancient, going back to at least Socrates.  Fiction can be a powerful tool for helping to think about society and economics in an easy manner.

Of course, what makes things difficult is keeping the comparison apt.  In Rousu’s article, he uses real world examples to make his case.  He relates actions in the book to actions in the real world that had similar outcomes.  If I wanted to write a fictional story about how communism makes everybody happy and well off, that would be significantly harder to relate to real life, as there are no examples to pick from.

I love fiction.  I love science fiction.  I love stories.  And I love economics.  When I can combine my loves, it makes for a good day.

On Precise Mathematical Models

Mathematics is the key and the gateway to the sciences.  Roger Bacon said these words some 750 years ago.  They are as true today as they were then.  But what is also important is wisdom: knowing what you don’t know and knowing the characteristics of what you are studying.

A few days ago, I was at the horse barn for my weekly horseback riding lesson.  My trainer and I were discussing different cues among horses (some horses are more responsive to human physical commands, some more so to voice commands.  Some will lope on a small command, and some need a hard command, etc).  She said that there is no book on how to rise a horse, no formula one can follow, it can only be learned though practice and it differs from horse to horse.

There is a certain science to riding a horse.  There are techniques and training methods.  There is experimentation.  But it is hardly as precise as, say, chemistry or biology (aka the hard sciences).

Horseback riding, like economics, is a social science.  We are dealing with living, breathing, creatures with free will.  There’s an element of randomness that comes into play.

Recognizing this randomness is what separates a good economist from a bad one, a good social scientist from a bad one.  Unfortunately, many economists forget this lesson.  They’re focused on their “precise mathematical models” (to use Noah Smith’s term), and forget the logic of thinking like an economist.

Models and experiments are very important.  They help shape our thoughts, and theories must be rigorously tested time and time again.  But social sciences, especially economics, is about looking for the unknown.  How many people who would have gotten jobs now can’t because of a minimum wage hike?  How much slower is economic growth because of new regulations?  How else would have funds been used if World War 2 not occurred?  Evaluating things while looking through the “broken window fallacy” lens is important.  That is why opportunity cost is one of the first things young economists are taught (and seemingly the first thing they forget).

This is not a right-wing-left wing thing, or a free market-command market thing, or an Austrian-Keynesian thing.  Economists on both sides make the mistake of becoming obsessed with models and mathematics and forgetting the basic economic lessons.

There’s a difference between knowing mathematics and knowing economics.  Many economists are competent with the former and not the latter.

The Virtues of Failure

Over at Cafe Hayek, Don Boudreaux has a great post on the virtues of entrepreneurship.  His post is full of the good side of successful entrepreneurship (let’s call that positive entrepreneurship).  But there is also good that comes from unsuccessful entrepreneurship (let’s call that negative entrepreneurship).

It’s weird to think of failure of having a good side.  For those who fail, it certainly doesn’t seem good.  For those who risked it all and lost, it can be hard to see the positive.  But failure teaches us what not to do.

Why is knowing what not to do important?  For the simple reason we do not live in Heaven.  Ours is a world of scarce resources.  There simply aren’t enough resources to satisfy every want out there.  So, we need to allocate our resources to their most productive uses.

And that is where failure comes in.  When schemes fail, it is a signal that the resources were not deployed in their most efficient manner.  They were not employed serving others’ or their owners’ needs.  Or their deployment was too costly, that there were other resources available that could meet the same need with less cost.

If failure is not allowed in an economy (say, firms are bailed out or protectionist tariffs are passed, or subsidies given), then the signals the failure provides are not properly transmitted.  This encourages the continued misuse of resources, diverting them from more useful causes and can lead to shortages.

Positive entrepreneurship is important, if it weren’t for success our lives would be stagnant, but we should not discount the learning process negative entrepreneurship provides.

Are Stagnant Real Wages Here To Stay?

Whenever income inequality comes up in discussions, someone inevitably cite stagnant real wages since about the 1980’s (that is, wages adjusted for inflation are largely unchanged over the past 30+ years).  This certainly is correct.  But, when determining an employee’s compensation, wages are only one aspect of it.  There are also benefits (health care, paid leave, vacation time, etc).  Putting it mathematically:

TC = W+B

TC = Total Compensation

W = Wages

B = Benefits

Real total compensation has been rising.  Given that the total is rising and one aspect (wages) is stagnant, this would suggest benefits are increasing as a share of total compensation.  In fact, this has been happening.  US government data (as reported by the Kaiser Foundation) shows wages’ share is falling (see Figure 2).  The Heritage Foundation confirms this trend.

Looking at this data, it is likely real wages up to this point were stagnant because of increasing benefits.  So, what does that mean for real wages going forward?

I postulate that, as more and more benefits increase (and indeed, some become mandatory), we will likely see real wages remain stagnant, and possibly even decline.  Should my hypothesis be correct, it could have dire consequences for employee policy prescriptions: programs like Obamacare, or mandatory parental leave, could actually increase income inequality for workers.  These kinds of programs could actually harm workers by reducing their monetary take-home pay.

Stagnant real wages may be the new normal.

How Regulation Can Kill Consumer Choice

One of my favorite shows on TV right now is Bob’s Burgers.  In Season 4, a single episode so perfectly captures regulatory concerns it’s almost as if an economist wrote it.

The episode is Season 4, Episode 7, “Bob and Deliver.”  In the episode, Bob is hired to be the home ec teacher at his kids’ school.  The kids in the class begin learning to cook and quickly become excellent chefs, to the point where the kids at school would rather spend their money at the “home ec-staurant” than at the cafeteria.  Of course, this infuriates the lunch ladies (who are employed not by the school but by a firm hired by the school to do the catering).  After several attempts to intimidate Bob to shut his class down, they eventually turn to the school, which promptly fires Bob, shuts down the home ec-staurant and forces the kids to eat the cafeteria food.  Bob and the kids stage a brief (and ultimately successful) revolt, but not without loss.

This episode, in 30 minutes, does an excellent job capturing the problems with regulation: regulatory capture (that is, a firm that is supposed to be controlled by the regulators eventually using them to suppress competition, like the way the lunch ladies do to Bob), loss of consumer choice (the students couldn’t choose whether to spend their money at the home ec-staurant or the cafeteria), and harm imposed onto the consumer (since the students couldn’t choose, they couldn’t choose the option that gave them the greatest welfare).

When free market economists like myself object to regulation, we have these very concerns in our mind.

Spontaneous Order In Action

This morning, my city suffered a rather large power outage.  Seeing as I couldn’t do anything at home (my kitchen and heat are electric), I decided to go out and do some errands.  But, wouldn’t ya know, the electric traffic lights were out, too.  Some of these lights were at fairly major intersections.  But here’s the interesting part: traffic was flowing pretty freely.  There were no accidents.  There were no issues.  And each intersection had its own rules, too.  Some intersections had a “first come, first served” style.  Others had a nice rotation where one car from each part of the intersection would go, and then it would move around the circle.  Everyone navigated this issue with no problems and went along their way.

This is an example of this “spontaneous order” I like to talk about.  Out of this chaotic mess of traffic, rules developed to govern the situation without any kind of forceful hand needed.  Each person’s desire to get through the intersection guided them to play by the rules no governing body set out, but rather arose naturally.

Ordo ab Chao!